Economic Issues Fit for the G8 at L'Aquila 2009
George M. von Furstenberg
J.H. Rudy Professor of Economics
Indiana University
G8 Research Group
vonfurst@indiana.edu
July 8, 2009
Groups
of advanced industrial countries, such as the G8, that engage in regular
exercises of joint decision-making in areas of systemic significance have been
pressed to extend membership to other countries regardless of their
qualifications. The inflation of the Gs is commonly driven by the alleged need
for greater inclusiveness and legitimacy. However, for a system of setting rules and imposing
standards to be legitimate does not require all the “stakeholders” that are
affected by the system to have a direct voice in its design. Often all that is
needed is that the system should pass the political and economic market test of
being widely adopted and also that it prove adaptable as innovative system
alternatives emerge.
To
clarify this point by analogy: producers and consumers of an item both have a
stake in its design and quality, but they generally do not get together
beforehand in market system to decide what is to be produced. Rather, producers
decide what they want to offer, and the reaction of consumers to that offer is
registered in the sales figures and profit margins achieved. Focus groups and
test marketing may reduce uncertainty about consumer acceptance, but it is
ultimately the market test where producers and consumer connect and learn in
what direction the invisible hand is pointing. Of course, the invisible hand
cannot rest its arm and point clearly if the market is allowed to function in a
way that does not serve to reveal crucial aspects of product quality and of user
or investor risk.
It
thus becomes clear that there are distinct roles for producers, the givers of
international public goods, and those who also utilize those public goods as
adopters or consumers. What then do the G8 have to give to a much greater
measure than broader groups?
- International Financial Regulation. The leaders of financial market
innovation and development necessarily are the ones who are qualified to engage
in systematic error learning and cumulative improvement of financial product,
institutions, and market regulations. They alone have a natural responsibility,
derived from technical competence in this area, to lead the way to expertly
improving prudential regulation, transparency, and incentive compatibility in
sound finance. The combination of securities-market based systems in the 3
“Anglo-Saxon” members of the G8 with highly developed bank-dominated systems in
France, Germany and Japan provides
sufficient breadth to design regulations compatible with, and applicable in,
both types of systems. With Switzerland not being a member of the G20, it is fair
to say that all non-G8 members of the G20 are solely consumers of these
regulations. Since consumer-producer cartels are undesirable and inefficient in
planning production, these other members will contribute nothing of value, and
perhaps waylay appropriate prompt action, at the design stage. Hence the G8 minus Russia is the natural
(law)giver for itself and the rest of the externally open world under capital-account
convertibility. Mending “fundamental weaknesses in the global economy related
to propriety, integrity and transparency”— in the language of the G8 Finance
Ministers’ Lecce Communiqué -- is the G7’s financial-order business.
- Fiscal Stimulus.
The advanced industrial countries have the capacity to take on greater public
debt without driving up the expected rate of inflation and long-term interest
rates in the present crisis. A few other countries, in particular China, South
Korea, and India, and to a lesser extent Russia and most non-G8 European
countries, also may have some of that capacity. Hence while the G8 is not
entirely inclusive of all producers who may safely be called upon to provide
increased fiscal stimulus, at least three-quarters of the world’s
countercyclical discretionary fiscal stimulus will be delivered by countries
which are members of the G8. Certainly no one would be looking for increased
fiscal stimulus from G20 countries like Argentina which are already in a
substantial external and domestic financial bind. Hence, with the exception of
the three Asian countries mentioned that are members of the G20 but not the G8,
the G8 comprises the group of countries in which fiscal stimulus primarily
needs to be planned. They, and not serial defaulters like Argentina, should
decide on the degree of temporary economic stimulus that is appropriate for them
and the world. What exit strategy to follow thereafter also is for them to
decide individually and collectively, and not usefully for any larger group.
- Monetary Stimulus Policy. The world level of real interest
rates on liquid dollar, euro, and yen-denominated instruments, and the rate of
inflation in the respective currency areas comprise the products of monetary
policy, interacting with market forces and expectations, which are important
for the world. In a few cases, such as China, monetary policy may affect a
systemically significant exchange rate and thereby impose exchange-rate
pass-through effects on other countries. Yet the monetary policy of most non-G8
countries is primarily of domestic consequence: It affects their country risk
premiums, inflation premiums, and interest rates. Hence again, the monetary
policy that is of global significance is provided by the G8 minus Russia;
monetary policy decisions even by large G20 countries like Indonesia and South
Africa tend to have little direct effect beyond their immediate economic
region. There is no point for producers of the coordinated G7 monetary policy
to negotiate that policy with all of its international consumers or to try to
agree on an exit strategy from central banks’ liquidity and balance-sheet
expansion with them beforehand.
The
G8 l’Aquila Communiqué on the Economy has centered on common action in the
three areas identified above. The G8 comprises the group of countries most
competent, and in some sense therefore most legitimate, to lay down the “law”
in these matters. This note has
tried to show that there is nothing functionally useful about arranging
consumer-producer groups like the G20 to decide on the best method of supplying
international public goods that should be adopted by the G8. It is for the
producers, and not those who only consume such goods, to determine for the G8
how much is to be supplied by when by each of its members. This does not mean that arguments and
pleas from non-G8 countries, like consumer suggestions and complaints in
business, should not be heard and carefully considered on their merits in the
G8’s own decision process.
All contents copyright © 2024. University of Toronto unless otherwise stated. All rights reserved.